Economic value of English law | Oxera

5.2: English law suffers from a type of ‘market failure’

Published: October 5th 2021
Chapter 5

5.2: English law suffers from a type of ‘market failure’


So far, this report has set out the significant economic benefits that English law brings to the UK, outside the legal services sector, by serving as an essential infrastructure to facilitate transactions in the economy.

Similarly to other types of infrastructure, English law is likely to suffer from ‘market failure’—i.e. a situation where society as a whole can be made better off if provision is not entirely left to private parties within the market (see Box 5.1 for a more detailed explanation). This problem arises because once a private party makes an effort to promote English law, all English law users— including both the legal services sectors, the businesses they serve, and the wider UK economy—will benefit from that effort without having to pay for it. The problem of those who benefit from resources or services of a communal nature[1]A resource or service of a communal nature is considered a public good if it satisfies two characteristics: non-rivalry (when a good is consumed, it does not reduce the amount available for others), … Continue reading but do not pay for them or under-pay is called the ‘free-rider’ problem.

Box 5.1. The economics of ‘market failure’

The term ‘market failure’ is used by economists to describe a situation where a market will under- or oversupply certain goods or services relative to the socially optimal level, leading to sub-optimal outcomes. The term therefore refers to how a market performs relative to a hypothetical benchmark widely used in the economics literature, and is not a reflection of the commercial success of legal service providers.Conceptually, a market where there are many firms (so no single firm can influence the price level significantly), no transaction costs (through perfect knowledge and information), homogeneous (i.e. the same) products, no externalities (i.e. the decisions of one firm or consumer do not have an impact on the welfare of other firms or consumers), and no barriers to entry can result in an economically efficient allocation of resources. However, there are many situations where this may not be the case—for instance:

  • when it is difficult for a private market to produce public goods efficiently due to the free‑rider problem;
  • when the existence of externalities means that the full social costs and benefits are not fully reflected in market prices.

In such cases, markets can lead to an inefficient allocation of resources (relative to the socially optimal benchmark).

In other words, these are situations where society as a whole can be made better off when the provision of a good or service is not left solely to a market. Therefore, this term refers to a ‘failure’ of the market to allocate resources in an economically efficient way. Economists use this concept to understand how markets function and it should not be taken to mean that any particular market is performing ‘well’ or ‘badly’.

Source: Oxera

Another way to look at the market failure that English law exhibits is that there is a positive externality coming from the use of English law—i.e. the benefits enjoyed by the wider UK economy from English law are beyond the benefits for the UK legal services sector.

A free market that works efficiently is expected to result in an optimal level of investment where the marginal cost of the investment equals its marginal benefit for all users. However, due to this positive externality, no private party—in this case, either within or outside the legal services sector—can capture all of the benefits enjoyed by the whole UK economy from the promotion of English law. Indeed, as the legal services sector receives only a part of the benefits generated by English law, the optimal level of investment made by that sector would be likely to fall short of the total benefits. This would then lead to an ‘under-provision’ of English law compared to the outcome without this market failure—i.e. the socially optimal level of investment that is consistent with all of the benefits English law brings to the UK economy.[2]Superficially, this free-rider problem as described in the case of English law has some similarity with the ‘tragedy of the commons’ concept. However, there are important differences between the … Continue reading)

This ‘under-provision’ problem is particularly relevant when there is large upfront investment required from a private company. The lack of incentives from the free market means that there is economic inefficiency—i.e. investments are not made even when the wider social marginal benefits exceed the marginal cost of the investments.

The economic inefficiency exists here because without sufficient investments to maintain and promote English law, some transactions may move away from English law to other governing laws, reducing the economic benefits that English law can bring to the UK. Perhaps more importantly, increased ‘efficiency’ would allow the UK economy to realise more fully the potential value that is on offer from further opportunities for English law (such as those described in section 4.4).

References

References
1A resource or service of a communal nature is considered a public good if it satisfies two characteristics: non-rivalry (when a good is consumed, it does not reduce the amount available for others), and non-excludability (it is not possible to provide a good without it being possible for others to enjoy it).
2Superficially, this free-rider problem as described in the case of English law has some similarity with the ‘tragedy of the commons’ concept. However, there are important differences between the two concepts. ‘Tragedy of the commons’ refers to the overuse/overconsumption of a common resource while the free-rider problem in English law refers to the lack of incentive to invest and supply a good. The free-rider problem in English law, therefore, is more similar to the issues of low R&D funding or investment in infrastructure projects. (The ‘tragedy of the commons’ idea originated in an essay written in 1833 by the British economist William Forster Lloyd, who used a hypothetical example of overgrazing on common land (also known as a ‘common’) in Great Britain and Ireland. It became widely known as the ‘tragedy of the commons’ after an article written by Garrett Hardin in 1968: Hardin, G. (2009). ‘The tragedy of the commons’, Journal of Natural Resources Policy Research, 1:3, pp. 243–53.